Showing posts with label Tickengo. Show all posts
Showing posts with label Tickengo. Show all posts

Saturday, April 6, 2013

WORKSHOP COMMENTS TO ORDER INSTITUTING RULEMAKING FILED BY BARRY KORENGOLD ON BEHALF OF THE SAN FRANCISCO CAB DRIVERS ASSOCIATON


Note - There have been some excellent arguments made on behalf of taxi drivers and the taxi industry at the CPUC hearings on "Rulemaking on Regulations Relating to Passenger Carriers, Ridesharing and New Online Transportation Services (NOETS)." In honor of these efforts I'm discarding my usual egotism and will be running some of them in my blog. This one is from Barry Korengold of the SFCDA. 

Opening Comments:

The San Francisco Cab Drivers Association (SFCDA) would like to register our strong objection to the biased and predetermined manner in which this proceeding is being conducted.  The stated goal of this proceeding was “to ensure that the law and the Commission’s safety oversight reflect the current state of the industry and these regulations are just and fair for all passenger carriers.”  Yet before the first round of comments to this proceeding were submitted or reviewed, the commission suspended its $20,000 citations and cease and desist orders to Uber and Lyft, giving both companies the go ahead to continue operating and advertising full steam ahead, regardless of existing law.  This action has allowed these companies to continue building their customer base at an rapidly expanded level, unfairly competing with law abiding taxicabs and charter party passenger carriers.  (Appendix A and B)

In taking this action, the Commission has ignored or neglected to consider the comments submitted by the Personal Insurance Federation of California which state clearly that vehicles operating for companies such as Lyft or Sidecar would not be covered by personal insurance policies, as they clearly operate on a “for profit” basis and are not “rideshare” services as defined in California Public Utilities Code Section 5353(h).  (Appendix C)
This action also ignores what the SFCDA pointed out in our initial comments, including the fact that although no “time based determination” may be cited in California Public Utilities Code Section 5360.5, it clearly states that charter party carriers of passengers shall operate on a prearranged basis, and that “prearranged basis” means transportation must be arranged by written contract or by telephone.  (Appendix D) At the time this was written, this was enough to ensure the intention of this law, which is the requirement of prearrangement.  Uber is now conflating the meaning of “by telephone” in this context, as being the same as “by smartphone”, which is actually a computer, with more processing power than was used by NASA to land a man on the moon.  

The use of a smartphone, which uses GPS and other technology that didn’t exist when this law was written, allows one to virtually see a vehicle around the corner or down the street and “hail” it for “on demand service”.  As we’ve already pointed out, Uber’s website even states their service is now “exclusively on demand”.  (Appendix E)  Given this context and the advancement of modern technology, we believe that in order to preserve the concept of prearrangement in the smartphone era, additional terminology specifying a minimum prearrangement time window is necessary.  We recommend a 30 to 60 minute advanced order requirement.

Thus far, the Commission has rewarded these rogue operations for defying the law.  It has become clear to those forced by necessity to participate in this proceeding that the outcome has been predetermined from the onset.


Should NOETS be regulated as taxicabs?

Absolutely.  As NOETS have been and continue operating as de facto taxicabs, they need to be regulated as such.  It is untenable to have different taxicabs, providing the same service, regulated by different entities and playing by different rules, simply because they label themselves something different.

The claim that NOETS such as Lyft and Sidecar are “rideshares” is completely false.  Whether the payment for rides are called “donations” or not, they are clearly “for profit” enterprises which provide taxi service. (Appendix F)  They are not merely providing transportation between home and work locations, nor to a destination incidental to another purpose of the driver, as specified in CPU Code 5353(h).

Lyft and Sidecar drivers spend hours on the road for no other reason than to pick up passengers and take them wherever they want for monetary compensation.  This behavior is encouraged and promoted actively by Lyft and Sidecar, despite contradictory claims to this commission.  These NOETS are not just “software companies” facilitating communication between individual drivers and people needing rides.  

Not only do they provide the means for payment and scheduling to these drivers, Lyft frequently hosts “Lyft Driver Hangouts” organized via a private Facebook page.  We have witnessed some of these “Hangouts” at SOMA Street Food and Mel’s Diner.  They even provide incentives to drivers who work during traditionally high taxi demand hours.  Unfortunately, since these are private pages, only registered drivers of these services are granted access to these pages.  

We have been able to obtain screenshots of some internal Lyft driver pages however, which mention these “Hangouts”. They also demonstrate these incentives and that drivers are working up to ten hour shifts. (Appendix G)

Other posts from Lyft drivers clearly indicate they see themselves as taxis and working “slow shifts”.  (Appendix H)

I personally had a passenger inform me that a Lyft driver told her she was able to quit her previous job now that she was driving for Lyft.  There are also these comments from Lyfts internal Facebook page: (Appendix I)

The suggested donation is not truly a donation, as there is a “suggested” amount, which does not just cover the cost of gas, bridge tolls and minor wear and tear of the vehicle.  Their suggested “donation” rates are clearly comparable to city regulated taxi fares, as demonstrated by this twitter from a Lyft administrator. (Appendix J)  The mere suggestions of these rates create substantial “peer” pressure to “donate”.  In fact, Lyft drivers are able to selectively avoid passengers who do not wish to “donate” enough. (Appendix K)

If a passenger neglects to actively input any payment amount to Sidecar, their credit card is automatically charged the “suggested donation”. (Appendix L)

Sidecar has also gone as far as providing a “heat map” of where potential taxi passengers are. (Appendix M)  

These drivers are unfairly competing with highly regulated and city permitted taxi drivers by not having to follow the same regulations and standards.  They are not required to carry the same insurance coverage, undergo the same level of background checks or partake in any required training.  Their vehicles are not required the same inspections or quality standards, they do not charge city standardized metered rates, nor do they follow any of the city’s Transportation Codes.


Public Safety:

As with most occupations, those who have not driven a cab for a length of time do not understand or appreciate the skills required to do it well.  Although most people can drive, a career driver who is on the road eight to ten hours a day, year after year, is a much safer driver than one who is not.  A professional driver is more skilled at hazard avoidance, knowledge of traffic laws and dealing with distractions, such as unruly and/or intoxicated passengers.  It is in the interest of public safety for cab driving to be a profession that retains skilled, knowledgeable career drivers, rather than one with low standards that attracts temporary workers with little to no experience spending their whole day on the road in city traffic.

If there are too many drivers vying for a limited number of passengers, this becomes a public safety hazard, as drivers get frustrated and race around looking for fares, jeopardizing pedestrians, bicyclists and other users of public rights of way.

Good drivers eventually quit and the quality of driver goes down.  If this happens, safety and service deteriorates even further for those who need it most (e.g., senior citizens and the disabled).


Should NOETS be regulated as passenger charter-party carriers?

No.  The CPUC does not have enough enforcement officers to ensure compliance and charter-party passenger carriers should only operate on a pre-arranged basis or they are essentially taxicabs.  Uber black car livery service should be regulated as a charter-party passenger carrier provided they are not operating on an “on demand” basis.

Public safety is better served when transportation for hire is regulated by local jurisdictions, as they have more resources for enforcement and a better ability to judge how those services should be regulated in the context of the local community.


Should NOETS represent a new transportation model requiring a Third Way regulatory approach?

No.  Taxicabs have been using smartphone apps for booking (and payments) before Uber, Sidecar, Lyft or Tickengo.  There is nothing new about using a smartphone app to hail a ride.  The NOETS are simply trying to avoid regulations required of legal taxicabs and charter-party passenger carriers.

If any new regulations were to be applied to NOETS operating as rideshares, the driver should have to post their intended destination with a departure time.  No more than the Internal Revenue Service business mileage standard plus any bridge tolls, divided by the number of passengers and driver, should be collected to cover the cost of the rideshare.  The 2013 IRS standard rate is 56.5 cents per mile. (Appendix N)

 A true rideshare should share the cost of each individual ride, not pay for the entire cost of vehicle ownership.  After all, these are personal vehicles, not primarily used for this purpose, as is a vanpool vehicle, defined in Section 5353(h).

Mitigating the costs of car ownership has been readily solved with services such as Zipcar.com and Citycarshare.org.  Lyft and Sidecar’s claims that they reduce congestion are in fact false, in that the riders that would normally take a different mode of transportation such as a taxi or mass transit are now in additional vehicles.  This causes the exact opposite effect and directly negates the positive impact of services such as Zipcar and Citycarshare.  Taxis that would normally be occupied are now driving around empty and cars that would normally be parked in a space or a driveway, are now constantly occupying transit only lanes and double-parked, either waiting for passengers or dropping them off.


Are NOETS either not subject to the CPUC’s jurisdiction, or is forbearance appropriate?

NOETS are absolutely subject to CPUC’s jurisdiction and forbearance is not appropriate, as Section 710(d) clearly does not exempt IP or VoIP’s from state or federal criminal or civil law, or any local ordinances:  

   (d) This section does not affect the enforcement of any state or federal criminal or civil law or any local ordinances of general applicability, including, but not limited to, consumer protection and unfair or deceptive trade practice laws or ordinances, that apply to the conduct of business, the California Environmental Quality Act (Division 13 (commencing with Section 21000) of the Public Resources Code), local utility user taxes, and state and local authority governing the use and management of the public rights-of-way.

The CPUC should determine that the NOETS must either conform to existing state regulations regarding charter party carrier or be subject to local regulations regarding taxis.  If they are to fall under ride-sharing as defined by CPUC code they must be limited to having a destination entered into the app prior to accepting passengers with a similar destination.

By extension, it would not be legal to sell drugs or run a prostitution ring because you use a smartphone app.  Those who transport passengers for hire over the public highways must still comply with governing laws, smartphone app or not.

For Appendices click on Read more.

Tuesday, March 5, 2013

My Reply Comments to the CPUC on Lyft, Sidecar & Willie Brown


Former San Francisco Mayor Willie Brown, representing Tickengo, has joined Lyft and Sidecar in their relentless attempts to square the circle of taxi and insurance regulations through the deliberate misuse and disingenuous re-definition of ordinary words. To give you some idea of what you’re in for if you read through Sidecar’s 25-page tome:

“ ... the ridesharing exemption does not apply if the ‘primary purpose of those persons is to make a ‘profit’ but there is no definition or any guidance on how to interpret the term ‘profit.’”

This reminds me of the old Bill Cosby routine where he dates a philosophy student who keeping asking him questions like, “What is air?”

The Facts

Lyft, Sidecar and Tickengo are commercial enterprises that profit (i.e. make money) from licensing phone apps to drivers and their customers. The way it works is that a customer uses an app to hail a driver. The driver accepts the hail, picks up the customer and takes him or her to a destination. The customer pays. The driver gets 80% and the companies get 20% of the payment.

Ten major auto insurers that I contacted, as well as the Personal Insurance Federation of California (PIFC), describe such business as either taxicab or livery services that are required to carry business or commercial insurance. The problem for Lyft, Sidecar and Tickengo is that they don’t want their drivers to have to pay commercial insurance rates and they don’t want to be regulated. Among the reasons why: 

  1. Commercial insurance is more expensive. The rate on my 2009 4-door Camry with $150,000 - $300,000 personal liability is $580 every six months. The quote I got for business use was $1,480.
  2. The California Highway Patrol's Motor Carrier Safety regulations require that charter party carriers, (i.e. cabs and limos, among other things), inspect and maintain the vehicles to ensure that they are in safe operating order.  (13 CCR § 1232.)  The CPUC requires charter-party carriers to maintain proper documentation of such inspections.  (CPUC Gen. Order 157-6 §4.02.) 

Since Lyft and Sidecar allow cars dating as far back as 2000, many of the vehicles would most certainly fail these inspections. This failure rate and the cost of these inspections, coupled with the high price of commercial insurance, would drastically reduce the available pool of drivers.

Denying that People Work for Money

Sidecar went into some detail on its strange concept of  “profit” with the following:

By its enforcement actions and policy, the CPSD (Public Utilities Commission's Consumer Protection Safety Division) has apparently chosen to interpret essential and undefined terms such as “profit” as narrowly as possible. The CPSD’s position is that only “incremental” or “variable” profit (i.e., on a per-trip basis) should be considered; however ... a reasonable and practical construction of profit and a commercial enterprise is the total expenses of operation (i.e., the fixed and variable or aggregate costs). Simply put, there’s no profit where total costs exceed income ...

Brilliant! Nobody has ever thought of that before.

Sidecar, then, is desperately trying to redefine “profit” into some murky arcane concept that nobody can understand. Common sense provides the obvious rebuttal to this self-serving re-definition . How many people would spend twenty or thirty hours a week running passengers here and there if they didn’t make money doing it?  

In addition, Lyft, Sidecar and Tickengo advertise for drivers by telling them that they will make money.   A Lyft ad says:

 "Make $22/hr With Your Car - Have A Car? Give A Lyft - lyft.me."  

The Sidecar driver application opens with:

"You drive every day. Why not get paid for it? Make extra cash and meet some awesome people by driving with SideCar! ... Some SideCar drivers are earning $22+ per hour."

Tickengo’s website is a little subtler and doesn’t mention money until the end of its driver page when it writes:

"Get Paid When you accept a ride, your passenger receives an electronic ticket with a PIN. Ask for this code once at destination to get paid. If the ride goes well, you'll get a good review, which means more requests and more money... Enjoy!"

Given that these are their own advertisements, no one should be surprised if the arguments that Lyft, Sidecar and Tickengo put forward to prove that their drivers don’t make a “profit” tend toward the esoteric.
The “Who Can Read Minds?” Denial
Sidecar writes:
"The ridesharing exemption under section 5353(h) provides for “[t]ransportation of persons between home and work locations or of persons having a common work-related trip purpose in a vehicle having a seating capacity of 15 passengers or less…and/or transportation that is “incidental to another purpose of the driver.... It is ... important that the phrase “the purpose of the driver” not be read too narrowly. A focus on driver’s state of mind would be so difficult to discern that it would create uncertainty and be impossible to enforce."
This was thought to be so profound that it was echoed by Willie Brown who wrote: 
“It would be impossible to read drivers’ minds and differentiate between people just helping out other people trying to recoup their vehicle expenses.”
Impossible to read drivers’ minds? Wouldn’t the fact that Lyft, Sidecar and Tickengo drivers transport customers for an average of $22 per hour be an indication of what’s going on in their heads?
“Work-related” means driving around while thinking about working.
Sidecar asks that the CPUC: 
“Clarify and ensure reasonable and practical guidance and commercially reasonable interpretations of certain vague and undefined ridesharing terms and phrases including “work-related” and “work locations.”  Such terms and phrases should not be construed narrowly based on outdated historical or traditional principles of an employer-employee relationship and a traditional “9-5” home- work commuting routine. ... Rather, the terms and phrases should be construed for the varied circumstances of the current California labor force and market. The CPSD has narrowly defined these terms through its enforcement policies and actions in a manner that is impracticable and unwarranted (i.e., suggesting that a driver or passenger must be an “employee” of an entity, thereby disqualifying independent contractors, freelancers, or full time moms/caregivers from the “work-related” element of the rideshare exemption).
If the rideshare exemption is not actually intended to refer to the act of sharing a ride between common destinations, as opposed to offering paid, on-demand transportation, and if the CPUC proves capable of accepting this kind of self-serving obfuscation of common language from the mouths of for-profit businesses -- from whom the CPUC is supposed to be protecting the public -- then I think I’ll start looking for housing in some neighborhood that is nowhere near a PG&E gas line.
Innocence by Association 
Willie Brown keeps lumping Tickengo together will a true, government-run ridesharing site, 511.org, in hopes that the reader will get the expression “ridesharing sites such as 511.org or Tickengo” stamped on his or her brain. In fact, Brown links Tickengo with 511.org at least seventeen times in eight pages.  But a quick glance at the 511.org website proves this connection a lie. Instead of advertising for drivers that get paid, a 511.org add says:

 “Carpooling can save you money by dividing the driving expenses between members of the carpool. You can split the costs evenly between people in the carpool or you can split expenses by how often you rotate driving duties. If everyone drives equally, no money needs to change hands. If you are strictly a passenger, you can pitch in your share for gas and other expenses.”

Indeed, in the carpooling situations that I’m familiar with, passengers usually will offer to pay a dollar for the bridge or the gas. The drivers certainly don’t make $22 per hour before or after expenses.

The Magic of Numbers

Lyft, Sidecar and Tickengo all propose that the AAA annual cost of vehicle ownership ($8,776 per year) be used as a standard to judge whether or not a driver should be considered to be doing ridesharing. In the words of Willie Brown: “It would be impossible to calculate the exact expense of every trip so this limitation guarantees that ridesharing drivers are not ‘driving for a living’ as commercial drivers.” Brown is saying, that until drivers make $8,776 a year they are doing ridesharing. Over that amount, they are considered cab or limo drivers.

What’s wrong with this sophistry?

The main thing wrong with Brown’s logic is that the law was set up for actual carpooling operations, not taxi or livery services that are pretending to be carpools like Lyft, Sidecar and Tickengo.  The purpose of the carpooling law was to help the environment by taking cars off the street, not by putting thousands more cars on it as Lyft, Sidecar and Tickengo are doing.

The figures being thrown around by Lyft, Sidecar and Tickengo bear no relationship to a real carpooling situation. Let’s look at what a real carpooling situation would look like, given that AAA estimates 2012 California driving costs for 2012 as $0.596 per mile driven, and using a real carpool ride from San Francisco to Oakland as an example:
  
    1. For a 15-mile trip across the Bay Bridge, according the AAA standard, the mileage and toll costs to the driver per year would be $2974.
    2.   This is a difference of $5802 from the AAA total annual vehicle costs.  If this is used by the CPUC as a measure of “ridesharing”: 
  • This hard-working carpool driver, who goes into the office on every weekday of the year without taking a sick day or single state or federal holiday, can earn some extra income by driving up an additional 9,735 miles after work (about 185 miles per week, every week of the year, or about one standard taxi shift per week) driving people around with a pink mustache on the front of the car without violating the concept of “ridesharing”; or
  • This carpool driver will have to collect $5.71 from every casual carpool “customer” to recoup their annual vehicle expenses at the AAA rate.  This is exactly $4.71 per person more than the going rate at every transbay carpool stand.
    1. In a real transbay casual carpool, the passengers will sometimes (not always) contribute a dollar each toward the toll.  This custom only developed when the Bridge District recently started charging toll for use of the carpool lane.  This vehicle owner who drives to the City might hope, then, to collect $520 from two daily passengers.  In that case the difference between what this driver might collect and the proposed annual vehicle cost standard is $8256.
  • This tireless hypothetical vehicle owner, by Sidecar, Lyft and Tickengo’s standards, is free to drive an additional two standard taxi shifts per week, every week of the year (266 miles per week) in order to earn back their vehicle expenses for the year.   
If Lyft, Sidecar and Tickengo drivers were to work eight hours per day with a 15 mile per hour average, vehicle expenses would be ($8.94 * 8 hours) or $71.52 per day. Using the AAA yearly limit of $8,776 as a measure, the illegal taxicabs of Lyft, Sidecar and Tickengo would be allowed to operate five days a week for twenty-four weeks (nearly six months per year), or half-time during an entire year before they reached their “ridesharing” limit.  At $22 per hour promised returns, these drivers would actually make $21,120, or $12,344 more than the cost of all of their annual personal vehicle expenses.  A free personal vehicle and $12,000 a year in cash for working  (i.e. “ridesharing”) part-time.  Not bad.

Now that is what I call a good working definition of the difference between illegal taxicabs like Lyft, Sidecar and Tickengo and a real carpool.

Another good definition of a real carpool would be a non-profit like 511.org that can't afford to pay Willie Brown $500 an hour to represent them.